Unfree Markets by Justene Hill Edwards

Unfree Markets by Justene Hill Edwards

Author:Justene Hill Edwards
Language: eng
Format: epub
Publisher: Columbia University Press


* * *

The eagerness with which enslavers and merchants scrambled to profit from enslaved peoples’ entrepreneurship only increased after the Panic of 1837. General unease increased among enslavers amidst the backdrop of economic uncertainty, in particular the cotton market’s unpredictability in the late 1830s. Economic forces compelled South Carolina planters to consider different ways in which to maintain their investments in monoculture as the international demand for Southern cotton waned. This volatility—or perhaps insecurity—affected cotton prices. Between 1837 and 1849, the price of short-staple cotton fluctuated between $0.05 and $0.10 per pound, the lowest prices since the beginning of the nineteenth century. Concurrently, global demand for Southern cotton weakened in the midst of financial turmoil. The cotton market’s instability challenged South Carolina planters’ enthusiasm not about cotton as an industry, but on cotton monoculture.58

Enslaved people endured more suffering when enslavers became dedicated to the cultivation of and profit from one product. When enslavers stopped providing food and raiment to them, bondspeople were coerced to spend their already meager free time cultivating not only food for themselves, but also other essential items for the entire plantation community. Though enslaved people were being compensated by enslavers and merchants for their independent cultivation, these same enslavers and merchants increasingly took advantage of these forced economic relationships to bilk slaves out of the fair market value of their goods.

Moreover, enslaved people absorbed slaveholders’ increasing dependence on them to both harvest record amounts of cotton and dedicate more of their free time toward income-generating work. Enslaved woman Margaret Bryant witnessed her mother, a skilled weaver, work day and night to “make up that cloth to please the obersheer [sic].” She also invested her free time weaving extra yarn to sell to other enslaved people and poor whites.59 She revealed that poor white men would “come there and buy cloth from Ma. Buy three or four yard.”60 In her cloth trade, when Bryant’s mother sold cloth to other enslaved people, she often did not receive money as compensation. Instead Bryant’s mother would receive hogs or other commodities as payment for her cloth.

In theory, enslaved peoples’ extra work as producers of goods for the market allowed enslavers to maintain a singular focus on monoculture. Ultimately, enslavers’ dedication to monoculture—first rice, then cotton—threatened plantation self-sufficiency. For example, a planter who neglected subsistence farming and forced enslaved people to focus singularly on cotton cultivation risked dependence on external growers to provide food for not only themselves, but their slaves and livestock as well. When slaveholders relied on and purchased necessary foodstuff from upper South states such as Virginia for the nutritional needs of their slaves, they risked undermining the financial stability of their plantation enterprises. This concern, however, did not deter enslavers from investing in cotton monoculture. The profits to be made from cotton were so seductive that slave owners, before the 1840s, ignored the clear benefits of subsistence farming.61

For enslaved people, however, neither the financial panic nor its causes thwarted their participation in trade with their enslavers or with local merchants.



Download



Copyright Disclaimer:
This site does not store any files on its server. We only index and link to content provided by other sites. Please contact the content providers to delete copyright contents if any and email us, we'll remove relevant links or contents immediately.