Explaining Social Behavior: More Nuts and Bolts for the Social Sciences by Jon Elster

Explaining Social Behavior: More Nuts and Bolts for the Social Sciences by Jon Elster

Author:Jon Elster
Language: eng
Format: mobi, pdf
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Published: 2015-07-30T14:00:00+00:00


14

Rationality and behavior

Ignoring the costs of decision making

The idea of rationality has a strong normative appeal. We want to have reasons – desires and beliefs in light of which the action appears as rational – for what we do. In fact, our desire to act for a reason – our deference to rationality – can be so strong as to induce irrational behavior. We may define hyperrationality as the propensity to search for the abstractly optimal decision, that is, the decision that would be optimal if we were to ignore the costs of the decision-making process itself. These costs are of three kinds: (1) the cost of the means of deciding, (2) the cost of the side effects of deciding, and (3) the opportunity costs of deciding, that is, the value of the other things one might have done instead of going through the decision process. Let me illustrate them briefly.

Hyperrationality through neglect of (1) could arise in comparison shopping when the (expected) savings from finding the lowest price is less than the money spent on transportation traveling from store to store. Tourists in the south of France cross the border to Spain to buy cheap cigarettes as if gasoline were free.1 Neglect of (2) could induce hyperrationality in contested child custody cases. The court may try to promote the interest of the child by determining which parent is more fit for custody.2 Once that issue has been settled, the court has a good reason for awarding custody to that parent. In the juridico-psychological process of ascertaining relative fitness, however, incalculable damage may be done to the child. A more rational procedure, given the aim to be achieved, might be to flip a coin or retain the traditional presumption of maternal custody.

Neglect of opportunity costs is illustrated in an observation by Dr. Johnson in a conversation with Boswell about which subjects children should be taught first: “Sir, it is no matter what you teach them first, any more than what leg you shall put into your breeches first. Sir, you may stand disputing which it is best to put in first, but in the mean time your breech is bare. Sir, while you are considering which of two things you should teach your child first, another boy has learnt them both.”3 Again, flipping a coin may be more rational. Or consider the doctor who arrives at the scene of an accident and has to decide what steps to take. Although he obviously needs to examine the patient, his behavior is self-defeating if he spends so much time on it that the patient dies under his hand. When confronted with a patient suffering from a chemical injury to the eye, “the ophthalmologist should not appreciate history-taking as his initial goal; instead, he must ‘shoot first and ask later’: details of injury are asked during or after the initial irrigation.” Others may have had the experience, when plucking berries, of looking so long for the best place that by the time they find it night is falling.



Download



Copyright Disclaimer:
This site does not store any files on its server. We only index and link to content provided by other sites. Please contact the content providers to delete copyright contents if any and email us, we'll remove relevant links or contents immediately.